Follow Us

Follow us on Twitter  Follow us on LinkedIn
 

05 May 2021

Vox Frankel: What three economists taught us about currency arrangements


Richard Cooper, Robert Mundell, and John Williamson made important contributions on a variety of topics in international economics throughout their careers, particularly in terms of how we think about currency arrangements.. reviewing their work and drawing lessons for policymakers today.

A generation of great international economists is passing from the scene. Richard Cooper died on 23 December 2020. An American, he was teaching his classes at Harvard until the very end. Robert Mundell, passed away on 4 April 2021. Originally Canadian; he was a winner of the Nobel Prize in economics. And John Williamson, on 11 April. Originally British, he had been the first scholar hired by the Peterson Institute for International Economics.

All three made important contributions on a variety of topics in international economics throughout their careers. Interestingly, all three coined memorable phrases that are still in common use, though not always as precisely as these scholars had originally intended.  

More specifically, all three played roles in the ongoing debate over the best currency arrangements. Should countries allow their foreign exchange rates to be determined freely by the private market, floating as the dollar, yen, pound, and most other major currencies do? Each of these three economists was unhappy with floating and made proposals for reform of the system. Should central banks fix their exchange rates, or even give up their independent currencies entirely, as the individual members of the euro have done? Or should they do something else?

Williamson and intermediate exchange rate regimes

John Williamson led the ‘something else’ camp. He believed in intermediate exchange rate regimes, that is, arrangements that give more flexibility than fixed rates but are more stable than free floating (Williamson 2000). Intermediate regimes are viable ways to achieve some  degree of partial exchange rate stability together with some degree of partial monetary independence (Frankel 2012). Contrary to common mis-interpretations of Mundell’s ‘Impossible Trinity’, this is true even for countries fully open to international capital flows (Fischer 2008).

One intermediate regime is a ‘crawling peg’, a phrase that Williamson contributed to the lexicon of international monetary economics in 1965 (Williamson 1981). Under this arrangement, especially popular in Latin America in the 1980s and early 1990s, countries decided to live with inflation by undertaking monthly mini-devaluations that kept their producers’ price-competitive on world markets. Even today, some developing countries like Nicaragua continue to use the crawling peg (Ilzetzki et al. 2019).

Williamson also championed another intermediate regime, the target zone, under which countries keep their exchange rates within pre-specified bands. He repeatedly refined and updated his proposals to apply the target zone even to the dollar, euro, yen, and other major currencies (Williamson 1987, 1994). In 1987, at the time of the Louvre Accord, a ‘reference range’ version of this proposal was secretly adopted by the G7 (Frankel 1990). But it was short-lived.

These intermediate exchange rate arrangements found their greatest popularity among emerging markets. Many of these countries mixed and matched Williamson features, falling under the rubric of Band-Basket-Crawl (or ‘BBC’) (Williamson 2001). Botswana and Singapore still do so today (IMF 2020).

Williamson’s greatest claim to fame stemmed from another expression that he coined, in 1989: the ‘Washington Consensus’ (Williamson 1993). He listed ten economic policies for developing countries that he judged had the support of the IMF, World Bank, and US administrations.  

He utterly lost control of his own invention, however. He had explicitly excluded one item from the list: the removal of financial controls. While pursuing the goal of keeping developing-country exchange rates competitive, he said, “there is relatively little support for the notion that liberalization of international capital flows is a priority objective”. Many subsequently would talk about the ‘Washington Consensus’, but most of them assumed that it entailed the opposite, the free movement of capital, typically in eager attacks on perceived ‘neoliberalism’.

Cooper, cooperation, and currencies

Richard Cooper can be judged to have favoured fixed exchange rates (Frankel 2020, Cooper 1999). His 1971 paper pointed out the adverse balance sheet effect that devaluation can have in developing economies (Cooper 1971).  

Further, he predicted that business would eventually find the high volatility of floating rates ‘intolerable’. In 1984, he made an uncharacteristically radical proposal for “the creation of a common currency for all of the industrial democracies,” beginning with the US, Europe, and Japan (Cooper 1984). To be sure, he emphasised that his plan was only a vision for the long term. But his notion of the long term was the 21st century. We are here. Yet the political appetite in each part of the world for giving up this sort of national sovereignty is even more miniscule now than it was when he made the proposal.

Perhaps Cooper was unrealistically optimistic about the practical prospects for international coordination in general. He had started the academic field of international macroeconomic interdependence and cooperation, while avoiding the use of game theory, which later came to dominate the field (Cooper 1968, 1969, 1985; Frankel 2015).   

But he drew practical lessons from the history of international cooperation in fighting contagious diseases, an especially relevant example today (Cooper 2001)). And, after all, he had accomplished the rare feat of taking his scholarly contributions and helping put them into practice on the world stage, as US Under Secretary of State for Economic Affairs in the Carter Administration (1977-1981). The most salient example was the 1978 Bonn Summit of G7 leaders, in which Cooper played an active role (G7 1978). There, Germany and Japan agreed with the US that the three would act as locomotives simultaneously pulling the rest of the world economy out of economic stagnation. In the global economy of 2021, the US and China are the locomotives.

Indeed, Cooper in this episode gave the world the phrase ‘locomotive theory’, which refers to fiscal expansion that is coordinated across countries in periods when the global economy is suffering from a deficiency of demand. The story is that Cooper on a visit to Japan described the three big economies as ‘engines’ pulling the global train; the word ‘locomotive’ came from a translation back into English of coverage in Japanese sources....

more at Vox



© VoxEU.org


< Next Previous >
Key
 Hover over the blue highlighted text to view the acronym meaning
Hover over these icons for more information



Add new comment